Sums and Differences of Functions

Sums and Differences of Functions

[ad_1]

Introduction
Economists are interested in the effects of change. Therefore, the concept of
the derivative of a function, which provides information about how a function
changes in response to changes in the independent variable, is an important
one in economic analysis. For example, the derivative of a production function
provides information about the manner in which the output of a production
process changes as the number of workers employed by the company changes.
Differentiation is the mathematical tool that allows us to quantify such rates of
change. As we will see in Chapter 7, differentiation is also an important tool in
the determination of the maximum or minimum values of economic functions
such as profit and cost.
In Chapter 2, some linear functions in economics such as linear demand
and supply functions were introduced. These functions are characterized by
their graphs being lines having a constant slope, i.e., the gradient is constant
irrespective of the value of the independent variable. We say that the rate
of change of the function is independent of the point where it is measured.
Furthermore, the slope or gradient of a linear function may be determined
by taking any two points on the straight line and calculating the ratio of the
change in the vertical direction with respect to the change in the horizontal
direction as the value of the independent variable increases. The corresponding
situation for a nonlinear function is quite different, however, and the rate of
change of a nonlinear function varies as one moves along the curve given by its
109
110 Elements of Mathematics for Economics and Finance
P
Q
Δx
tangent at P
R
y=f(x)
Δy
Figure 6.1 The graph of a nonlinear function in which the tangent at the
point P is drawn.
graph.
In Fig. 6.1, we show part of the graph of a nonlinear function y = f(x).
On this graph, we have drawn the tangent to the curve at the point P. The
tangent to a curve at a point P is the straight line that passes through P and
that just touches the curve at this point. The slope or gradient of a curve
y = f(x) at P is then defined to be the gradient of the tangent to the curve
at P. It is a measure of the prevailing rate of change of y relative to x at P.
We can see from Fig. 6.1 that the gradient of a nonlinear function varies as we
move along the curve.
In mathematics, we use the notation f(a) (pronounced f primed of a) to
represent the slope of the tangent to the function f at x = a. The slope of the
tangent to a function is called the derivative of the function – corresponding
to each value of x there is a uniquely defined derivative f(x). Therefore, the
derivative of a function of x is also a function of x.
If y = f(x), then an alternative notation for the derivative of a function is
dy
dx
.
This is pronounced ‘dee y by dee x’. Note that this is a single entity not to

  1. Differentiation 111
    be manipulated in any sense and represents the derivative of y with respect to
    x. If, for example, f(x) = x2, then it is natural to use f(x) to represent the
    derivative of f(x), whereas if y = x2 is used then dy/dx is more appropriate.
    Consider the function y = f(x). The graph of this function is shown in
    Fig. 6.1. The slope or gradient of the function at the point P : (x, f(x)) is
    the slope of the tangent to the graph of the function at P (see Fig. 6.1). This
    slope can be approximated by the slope of the chord PQ where Q is the point
    (x + Δx, f(x + Δx)). (A chord is a straight line joining any two points on a
    curve.) So the horizontal distance from P to Q is Δx. If x is a variable, the
    notation Δx will denote a small change in x. Therefore,
    the slope of PQ = QR
    PR
    = f(x + Δx) − f(x)
    (x + Δx) − x
    = f(x + Δx) − f(x)
    Δx
    If Q is allowed to approach P in which case Δx approaches 0, the slope of the
    chord PQ approaches the slope of the tangent at P, i.e.,
    Slope of the Tangent at P = lim
    Δx→0
    f(x + Δx) − f(x)
    Δx
    . (6.1)
    The value of this limit, if it exists, is known as the derivative of the function
    f at x and is written f(x) or dy/dx. Thus, we have
    f
    (x) = lim
    Δx→0
    f(x + Δx) − f(x)
    Δx
    . (6.2)
    So the derivative of a function at a point is the ratio of the change in y to the
    change in x between the point and a point that it infinitesimally close to it. So
    the derivative measures the instantaneous rate of change of the function.
    If Δy denotes the change y corresponding to the change Δx in x, then
    Δy = f(x + Δx) − f(x),
    with f(x + Δx) being the value of y = f(x) when the value of x changes to
    x + Δx. Therefore,
    f
    (x)

    or dy
    dx

    = lim
    Δx→0
    Δy
    Δx
    . (6.3)
    Therefore, for a small change Δx in x and corresponding small change Δy in
    y, we have that
    dy
    dx
    ≈ Δy
    Δx
    ,
    112 Elements of Mathematics for Economics and Finance
    or
    Δy ≈ Δx

    dy
    dx

    . (6.4)
    This makes sense if dy/dx is regarded as the rate of change of y relative to x. In
    particular, dy/dx can be regarded as approximately the change in y resulting
    from a 1 unit increase in x (provided the value of x is relatively large so that
    1 unit is relatively small). The approximation (6.4) is known as the small
    increments formula.
    The process of finding the derivative of a function is known as differentiation.
    The definition of a function may be used to determine the derivative of
    a given function. This process is known as differentiation from first principles.
    For example, if f(x) = x2, then using (6.2) we have
    f
    (x) = lim
    Δx→0
    (x + Δx)2 − x2
    Δx
    = lim
    Δx→0
    (x2 + 2xΔx + (Δx)2) − x2
    Δx
    = lim
    Δx→0
    2xΔx + (Δx)2
    Δx
    = lim
    Δx→0

    2xΔx
    Δx
    +
    (Δx)2
    Δx

    = lim
    Δx→0
    (2x + Δx)
    = 2x.
    The process of determining the derivative of a function from first principles
    can be quite time consuming and involve lengthy mathematical calculations.
    Fortunately, there is a more rapid route to determining the derivative of the
    sorts of functions that we encounter in economics based on a number of rules,
    known as rules of differentiation. Some of these rules will be derived in the next
    section using the definition of the derivative of a function (6.2), but others will
    be stated simply without justification.
    Example 6.1
    Differentiate y = f(x) = x2 and use the small increments formula to estimate
    the change in y if x changes from 1 to 1.01. Calculate also the actual change
    in y.
  2. Differentiation 113
    Solution. We have already shown that dy/dx = f(x) = 2x and so f(1) = 2.
    If x increases from 1 to 1.01, then Δx = 0.01. Therefore, we can estimate the
    change in y using the small increments formula (6.4) as
    Δy ≈ Δx × f
    (1) = 0.01 × 2 = 0.02.
    The actual change Δy in y is f(1.01) − f(1) = 1.0201 − 1 = 0.0201.
    6.2 Rules of Differentiation
    In this section, we show how to differentiate functions without having to use
    the definition (6.2). A few rules are sufficient to differentiate all the functions
    encountered in this book.
    6.2.1 Constant Functions
    Consider the constant function f(x) = k, where k is a constant. Using the
    definition of a derivative (6.2), we have
    f
    (x) = lim
    Δx→0
    f(x + Δx) − f(x)
    Δx
    = lim
    Δx→0
    k − k
    Δx
    = lim
    Δx→0
    0
    Δx
    = 0.
    Thus, if f(x) = k then f(x) = 0. For example, if f(x) = 8, then f(x) = 0.
    This rule is obvious if f(x) is regarded as the rate of change of f(x) relative
    to x. In this case, f(x) is constant.
    114 Elements of Mathematics for Economics and Finance
    6.2.2 Linear Functions
    Consider the linear function f(x) = ax+b, where a and b are constants. Using
    the definition of a derivative (6.2), we have
    f
    (x) = lim
    Δx→0
    f(x + Δx) − f(x)
    Δx
    = lim
    Δx→0
    (a(x + Δx) + b) − (ax + b)
    Δx
    = lim
    Δx→0
    aΔx
    Δx
    = lim
    Δx→0
    a
    = a.
    Thus, if f(x) = ax + b then f(x) = a. This is the linear function rule. For
    example, if f(x) = 3x+2, then f(x) = 3, and if f(x) = 5−1
    4x, then f(x) = −1
    4 .
    6.2.3 Power Functions
    Consider the power function f(x) = kxn, where k is a constant and n is any
    real number. The derivative of this power function is given by f(x) = knxn−1.
    So to obtain the derivative of a power function, we multiply it by the power
    and reduce the original power by one. For example, if f(x) = 4×3, then f(x) =
    4×3×x3−1 = 12×2, and if f(x) = x4, then f(x) = 4×4−1 = 4×3. When k = 1,
    an important special case of this rule is realized, i.e., if f(x) = xn, then
    f
    (x) = nxn−1. (6.5)
    This rule, known as the power function rule, is derived using the definition
    (6.2). Since it involves the expansion of (x + Δx)n and some algebra, we omit
    the details here.
    6.2.4 Sums and Differences of Functions
    The rules we have introduced so far can be used to generate the derivatives of
    polynomials, the terms of which are power functions. Consider the function f,
    which is the sum of two functions g and h, i.e., f(x) = g(x) + h(x). Using the
  3. Differentiation 115
    definition of a derivative (6.2) we have
    f
    (x) = lim
    Δx→0
    f(x + Δx) − f(x)
    Δx
    = lim
    Δx→0
    (g(x + Δx) + h(x + Δx) − (g(x) + h(x))
    Δx
    = lim
    Δx→0
    (g(x + Δx) − g(x)) + (h(x + Δx) − h(x))
    Δx
    = lim
    Δx→0
    (g(x + Δx) − g(x))
    Δx
  • lim
    Δx→0
    (h(x + Δx) − h(x))
    Δx
    = g
    (x) + h
    (x).
    Thus, if f(x) = g(x) + h(x), then
    f
    (x) = g
    (x) + h
    (x).
    This is intuitively clear when derivatives are viewed as rates of change: the rate
    of change relative to x of two functions of x is the sum of their rates of change.
    Similarly, we can show that if f is the difference of two functions g and h, i.e.,
    f(x) = g(x) − h(x), then
    f
    (x) = g
    (x) − h
    (x).
    Thus, the derivative of a sum of two functions is equal to the sum of the
    derivatives of the individual functions. Similarly, the derivative of the difference
    of two functions is equal to the difference of the derivatives of the two functions.
    For example, if f(x) = 12×5 − 4×4, then f(x) = 60×4 − 16×3, and if f(x) =
    9×2 + 2x − 3, then f(x) = 18x + 2.
    Example 6.2
    Differentiate each of the following functions:
  1. f(x) = 9x − 6,
  2. y = −9x−4,
  3. f(x) = x8 + 8×6 + 11.
    116 Elements of Mathematics for Economics and Finance
    Solution.
  4. This is a linear function (see Section 6.2.2) with a = 9 and b = −6. Therefore,
    using the linear function rule, we have f(x) = 9.
  5. This is a power function (see Section 6.2.3) with k = −9 and n = −4.
    Therefore, using the power function rule, we have
    dy
    dx
    = (−9)(−4)x
    −4−1 = 36x
    −5 =
    36
    x5 .
  6. This is an example of a polynomial function comprising two power functions
    and a constant function. Therefore, using the rule for the sum of functions
    in conjunction with the power function and constant function (see Section
    6.2.1) rules, we have
    f
    (x) = 8×8−1 + 8 × 6×6−1 + 0 = 8×7 + 48×5.
    Note that the linear function rule can be deduced from a combination of
    the rule for the differentiation of the sum of two functions and the constant
    function and power function rules.
    6.2.5 Product of Functions
    Suppose that y = uv where u and v are functions of x. Let Δu, Δv, and Δy
    denote very small changes in u, v, and y, respectively, that correspond to a
    small change Δx in x. Then
    y + Δy = (u + Δu)(v + Δv)
    = uv + uΔv + vΔu + ΔuΔv.
    Since y = uv,
    Δy = uΔv + vΔu + ΔuΔv.
    We can ignore the term ΔuΔv since it is the product of two very small changes
    and therefore negligible. Therefore,
    Δy
    Δx
    = u
    Δv
    Δx
  • v
    Δu
    Δx
  • Δu
    Δx
    Δv.
    As Δx → 0,
    Δy
    Δx
    → dy
    dx
    ,
    and
    u
    Δv
    Δx
  • v
    Δu
    Δx
  • Δu
    Δx
    Δv → u
    dv
    dx
  • v
    du
    dx
    ,
  1. Differentiation 117
    since (Δu/Δx)Δv → 0 as Δx → 0. Thus, we obtain the product rule for
    differentiation: if y = uv, then
    dy
    dx
    = u
    dv
    dx
  • v
    du
    dx
    . (6.6)
    6.2.6 Quotient of Functions
    Suppose that y = u/v where u and v are functions of x. Let Δu, Δv, and Δy
    denote small changes in u, v, and y, respectively, that correspond to a very
    small change Δx in x. Thus Δu → 0 and Δv → 0 as Δx → 0. Then
    y + Δy = u + Δu
    v + Δv
    .
    Subtracting y = u/v from both sides of this equation yields
    Δy = u + Δu
    v + Δv
    − u
    v
    .
    Simplifying the fraction on the right-hand side of this equation gives
    Δy = v(u + Δu) − u(v + Δv)
    v(v + Δv)
    = vΔu − uΔv
    v(v + Δv) .
    Therefore,
    Δy

Δx

v Δu
Δx
− uΔv
Δx
v(v + Δv) .
Finally, letting Δx → 0, we obtain the quotient rule for differentiation: if
y = u/v then
dy

dx

v du
dx
− udv
dx
v2 . (6.7)
6.2.7 The Chain Rule
Suppose that y is a function of u, i.e., y = f(u), and that u in turn is a function
of x, i.e., u = g(x). We say that y is a function of a function and to express y
as a function of x we write
y = f(g(x)).
If Δy and Δu denote changes in y and u, respectively, that correspond to a
small change Δx in x, then
Δy
Δx
= Δy
Δu
Δu
Δx
.
118 Elements of Mathematics for Economics and Finance
Then, as Δx → 0, we obtain the so-called chain rule:
dy
dx
= dy
du
du
dx
= f
(u)g
(x). (6.8)
We may also write this in terms of derivatives of f and g and then express the
result solely in terms of a function of x, i.e.,
dy
dx
= f
(g(x))g
(x). (6.9)
As an illustration of the use of the chain rule to obtain the derivative of a
function, consider y = (x2 + 3x + 2)5. If we let u = x2 + 3x + 2, then y = u5.
Differentiating u with respect to x and y with respect to u, we obtain
dy
du
= 5u4,
du
dx
= 2x + 3.
Then using the chain rule yields
dy
dx
= dy
du
du
dx
= 5u4(2x + 3)
= 5(x2 + 3x + 2)4(2x + 3).
If we put x = y in (6.8), we obtain
dy
dy
= 1 = dy
du
du
dy
.
It follows that
du

dy

1
dy
du
. (6.10)
Example 6.3
Find the derivative of each of the following functions:

  1. f(x) = (2×3 + 1)(x2 − 3x) and evaluate f(1),
  2. f(x) =
    5×2 + 3
    x2 + 1
    and evaluate f(0),
  3. y = (7×4 + 2)6 and evaluate dy/dx when x = 0.
  4. Differentiation 119
    Solution.
  5. To differentiate this function, we use the product rule with u = 2×3 + 1
    and v = x2 − 3x. Now du/dx = 6×2 and dv/dx = 2x − 3. Therefore, using
    the product rule (6.6), we have
    f
    (x) = (2×3 + 1)(2x − 3) + 6×2(x2 − 3x),
    which, after some simplification, gives
    f
    (x) = 10×4 − 24×3 + 2x − 3.
    Finally, f(1) = 10 − 24 + 2 −3 = −15.
  6. To differentiate this function, we use the quotient rule with u = 5×2 + 3
    and v = x2 + 1. Now du/dx = 10x and dv/dx = 2x. Therefore, using the
    quotient rule (6.7), we have
    f
    (x) =
    (10x)(x2 + 1) − (5×2 + 3)(2x)

(x2 + 1)2

10×3 + 10x − 10×3 − 6x

(x2 + 1)2

4x
(x2 + 1)2 .
Evaluating this derivative when x = 0 gives f(0) = 0.

  1. To differentiate y = (7×4+2)6, we use the chain rule (6.8). Let u = 7×4+2
    then y = u6. Now
    dy
    du
    = 6u5,
    du
    dx
    = 28×3.
    Therefore,
    dy
    dx
    = (6u5)(28×3) = 168(7×4 + 2)5×3.
    When x = 0, dy/dx = 0.
    6.3 Exponential and Logarithmic Functions
    Let f be the exponential function f(x) = eg(x), where g(x) is some function of
    x. Then the derivative of f is
    f
    (x) = g
    (x) eg(x). (6.11)
    For example, if f(x) = ex2, then f(x) = 2xex2 since g(x) = x2 and g(x) =
    2x. When g(x) = 1, we have the important result that the derivative of the
    120 Elements of Mathematics for Economics and Finance
    exponential function ex is itself, i.e., ex, since g(x) = 1. More generally, if
    f(x) = ekx, where k is a constant, then
    f
    (x) = kekx.
    For example, if f(x) = e−2x, then f(x) = −2e−2x.
    Let f be the natural logarithmic function f(x) = lng(x), then the derivative
    of f is
    f
    (x) = g(x)
    g(x) . (6.12)
    For example, if f(x) = ln 6×2 then
    f
    (x) =
    12x
    6×2 =
    2
    x
    since g(x) = 6×2 and g(x) = 12x. When g(x) = x we have the result that the
    derivative of ln x is 1/x since g(x) = 1.
    We display these rules in Table 6.1.
    Example 6.4
    Find the derivative of each of the following functions:
  2. f(x) = 3e7−2x,
  3. f(x) = ln(x2 + 6x + 2).
    Solution.
  4. If f(x) = 3e7−2x, then g(x) = 7 − 2x. Since g(x) = −2, then
    f
    (x) = 3g
    (x)eg(x) = −6e7−2x.
    Table 6.1 Derivatives of the exponential and logarithmic functions.
    f(x) f(x)
    eg(x) g(x)eg(x)
    ex ex
    ln g(x) g(x)
    g(x)
    ln x
    1
    x
  5. Differentiation 121
  6. If f(x) = ln(x2 + 6x + 2), then g(x) = x2 + 6x + 2. Since g(x) = 2x + 6,
    then
    f
    (x) = g(x)

g(x)

2x + 6
x2 + 6x + 2.
6.4 Marginal Functions in Economics
6.4.1 Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost
Sometimes in economics, we are interested in the effect on total revenue, TR,
of a change in the value of Q. To do this, the concept of marginal revenue is
introduced. The marginal revenue of a good, MR, is defined by
MR = d(TR)
dQ
.
The marginal revenue function measures the instantaneous rate of change in total
revenue, TR, compared with demand, Q. For example, the marginal revenue
function, MR, corresponding to
TR = 100Q − 2Q2
is given by
MR = d(TR)
dQ
= 100 − 4Q.
If the current demand is 15, say, then
MR = 100 − 4 × 15 = 40.
This means that when demand is changed slightly from its current value of 15,
the corresponding change in total revenue is 40 times as large. However, if the
demand is 20, then
MR = 100 − 4 × 20 = 20,
which means that when demand is changed slightly from Q = 20, the corresponding
change in total revenue is only 20 times as large.
Economists say that MR is approximately the change in TR resulting from
a one unit increase in demand Q. In general,
Δ(TR) ≈ MR× ΔQ.
(This is just a consequence of the small increments formula (6.4).) This approximation
is a good one provided the quantities of Q involved are very large
122 Elements of Mathematics for Economics and Finance
so that one unit is relatively very small. An analogous statement can be made
regarding marginal cost, MC.
The marginal cost function, MC, is defined by
MC = d(TC)
dQ
. (6.13)
The average cost function, AC, is defined by
AC = TC
Q
. (6.14)
Example 6.5
If the average cost function for a good is
AC =
24
Q

  • 15 + 3Q,
    find an expression for the total cost function. What are the fixed costs in this
    case? Write down an expression for the marginal cost function.
    Solution. To find an expression for TC, we use the formula for AC given by
    (6.14). Hence

TC = AC × Q


24
Q

  • 15 + 3Q

    Q
    = 24+15Q + 3Q2.
    Since TC = FC + (V C)Q, the fixed cost element of the total cost function is
    independent of Q. Therefore, in this example the fixed costs are 24. Finally,
    an expression for the marginal cost function is obtained by differentiating TC
    with respect to Q. Therefore,
    MC = d(TC)
    dQ
    = 15+6Q.
    Note that the fixed costs have no influence on the marginal cost function since
    the derivative of a constant is zero.
  1. Differentiation 123
    6.4.2 Marginal Propensities
    The relationship between consumption C and national income Y is sometimes
    of the form
    C = f(Y ),
    where f is some appropriate consumption function. Of interest is the effect on
    C due to variations in Y , i.e., if national income rises by a certain amount,
    what effect does this have on the spending patterns of the population. This
    is analyzed using the concept of marginal propensity to consume, MPC,
    defined by
    MPC = dC
    dY
    ,
    i.e., the marginal propensity to consume is the derivative of consumption with
    respect to income. For example, if the consumption function is
    C = 0.01Y 2 + 0.2Y + 50
    to calculate MPC when Y = 30, we have
    MPC = dC
    dY
    = 0.02Y + 0.2.
    When Y = 30, MPC = (0.02)(30) + 0.2 = 0.8.
    Economists say that MPC is approximately the change in consumption due
    to a one unit increase in national income Y . More generally, if national income
    increases by a small amount ΔY , then the corresponding small change ΔC in
    consumption is approximately MPC × ΔY , i.e.,
    ΔC ≈ MPC × ΔY.
    If national income is used up only in consumption and savings, then
    Y = C + S.
    If we differentiate both sides of this equation with respect to Y :
    dY
    dY
    = dC
    dY
  • dS
    dY
    ,
    i.e.,
    1 = MPC + MPS,
    where
    MPS = dS
    dY
    is the marginal propensity to save. Economists say that MPS is approximately
    the change in savings due to a one unit increase in national income Y .
    124 Elements of Mathematics for Economics and Finance
    More generally, we can show, using the small increments formula again, that
    if national income increases by a small amount ΔY , then the corresponding
    small change ΔS in savings is given by
    ΔS ≈ MPS × ΔY.
    Thus if we knowMPC, we can easily determineMPS. In the above example
    the value of MPS when Y = 30 is given by
    1 = 0.8 + MPS
    i.e.,
    MPS = 0.2.
    This indicates that when income increases by one unit (from its current level of
    30), consumption rises by approximately 0.8 units, whereas savings rise by approximately
    0.2 units. At this level of income, the nation has a greater propensity
    to consume than it has to save.
    Example 6.6
    If the consumption function is
    C = 0.005Y 2 + 0.3Y + 20,
    calculate the marginal propensities to consume and save when Y = 10 and give
    an interpretation of the results.
    Solution. The marginal propensity to consume is defined by
    MPC = dC
    dY
    = 0.01Y + 0.3.
    When Y = 10,
    MPC = 0.01 × 10 + 0.3 = 0.1 + 0.3 = 0.4.
    If national income is used up in consumption and savings only, then
    MPC +MPS = 1.
    When Y = 10, the marginal propensity to save is
    MPS = 1−MPC = 1− 0.4 = 0.6.
    Therefore, at this level of national income, the nation has a greater propensity
    to save than it has to consume.
  1. Differentiation 125
    6.5 Approximation to Marginal Functions
    The exact value of MR at the point Q0 is given by
    d(TR)
    dQ
    ,
    and so is given by the slope of the tangent to the total revenue function at A
    (see Fig. 6.2). The point B also lies on the curve – it corresponds to a one unit
    increase in Q, i.e., ΔQ = 1. The vertical distance from A to B therefore equals
    the change in TR when Q increases by one unit. The slope of the chord joining
    A to B is
    Δ(TR)
    ΔQ
    = Δ(TR)
    1
    = Δ(TR).
    Note that the slope of the tangent is approximately the same as that of the
    chord joining A and B. Therefore, the latter produces a reasonable approximation
    to MR in many cases.
    This approximation holds for any value of ΔQ. Therefore, as we have seen
    in Section 6.4.1
    MR ≈ Δ(TR)
    ΔQ
    , (6.15)
    or
    Δ(TR) ≈ MR× ΔQ, (6.16)
    i.e., change in total revenue ≈ marginal revenue × change in demand. Note
    that if the total revenue function is linear, then we have equality: Δ(TR) =
    MR× ΔQ.
    TR
    Q
    A
    B
    tangent
    Qo Qo+ΔQ
    ΔQ
    Δ(TR)
    Figure 6.2 Approximation to marginal revenue.
    126 Elements of Mathematics for Economics and Finance
    Example 6.7
    If the total revenue function of a good is given by
    100Q − Q2,
    write down an expression for the marginal revenue function. If the current
    demand is 60, estimate the change in the value of TR due to a two unit increase
    in Q.
    Solution. To determine the marginal revenue function, we differentiate the
    total revenue function. Therefore,
    MR = d(TR)
    dQ
    = 100 − 2Q.
    When Q = 60,
    MR = 100 − 2 × 60 = 100 − 120 = −20.
    When there is a two unit increase in Q, i.e., ΔQ = 2, then the estimated change
    in TR is given by
    Δ(TR) ≈ MR× ΔQ = −20 ×2 = −40,
    i.e., there is an estimated 40 unit reduction in TR.
    A similar approximation to (6.15), using the small increments formula (6.4),
    holds for the marginal cost function:
    MC ≈ Δ(TC)
    ΔQ
    , (6.17)
    or
    Δ(TC) ≈ MC × ΔQ, (6.18)
    i.e., change in total cost ≈ marginal cost × change in demand. Note that we
    have equality if the total cost function is linear, then Δ(TC) = MC × ΔQ.
    Example 6.8
    Find the marginal cost function given the average cost function
    AC =
    100
    Q
  • 2.
    Deduce that a one unit increase in Q will always result in a two unit increase
    in TC, irrespective of the current level of output.
  1. Differentiation 127
    Solution. To determine the marginal cost function, it is first necessary to find
    an expression for the total cost function, TC. Now TC and AC are related by
    AC = TC
    Q
    ,
    and therefore
    TC = AC × Q =

    100
    Q
  • 2

    Q = 100 + 2Q.
    The corresponding marginal cost function is
    MC = d(TC)
    dQ
    = 2.
    Since TC is a linear function, we have Δ(TC) = MC × ΔQ. Therefore, if
    output increases by one unit, i.e., ΔQ = 1, then
    Δ(TC) = 2,
    irrespective of the current level of output.
    6.6 Higher Order Derivatives
    We have already seen that the derivative of a function of x is itself a function of
    x. This suggests the possibility of differentiating a second time to get the ‘slope
    of the slope of a function’. This is written as f(x) or d2y/dx2. This function
    is known as the second order derivative of f(x). Higher order derivatives are
    found by applying the rules of differentiation to lower order derivatives. The
    third order derivative f(x) or d3y/dx3 measures the slope and rate of change
    of the second order derivative, etc. Thus, if
    f(x) = 2×4 + 5×3 + 3×2,
    we have
    f
    (x) = 8×3 + 15×2 + 6x
    f
    (x) = 24×2 + 30x + 6
    f
    (x) = 48x + 30
    f(4)(x) = 48
    f(5)(x) = 0
    128 Elements of Mathematics for Economics and Finance
    Example 6.9
    For each of the following functions, find the second derivative and evaluate it
    at x = 2.
  1. f(x) = x6 + 3×4 + x,
  2. y = 2×2 + 38x − 6,
  3. y = (8x − 4)6.
    Solution.
  4. To differentiate this polynomial function, we use a combination of the rule
    for the sum of functions and the power function rule. So
    f
    (x) = 6×6−1 + 3 × 4×4−1 + 1
    = 6×5 + 12×3 + 1.
    Differentiating a second time gives
    f
    (x) = 6× 5×5−1 + 12 × 3×2−1 + 0
    = 30×4 + 36×2
    Evaluating the second derivative when x = 2, we have
    f
    (2) = 30(24) + 36(22) = 624
  5. To differentiate this quadratic function, we use a combination of the rule
    for the sum of functions and the power function rule. So
    dy
    dx
    = 2× 2×2−1 + 38
    = 4x + 38.
    Differentiating a second time gives
    d2y
    dx2 = 4
    At x = 2, d2y
    dx2 = 4.
  6. To differentiate this function, we use the chain rule. Let u = 8x − 4, then
    y = u6. Since
    dy
    du
    = 6u5, and du
    dx
    = 8,
  7. Differentiation 129
    we have, using the chain rule
    dy
    dx
    = dy
    du
    du
    dx
    = 6u5 × 8 = 48(8x − 4)5.
    Applying the chain rule a second time gives
    d2y
    dx2 = 48 × 5u4 × 8 = 1920(8x − 4)4.
    Evaluating the second derivative when x = 2 gives
    d2y
    dx2 = 39813120.
    6.7 Production Functions
    In one of the simplest models for production, the quantity of output produced,
    Q, is assumed to be a function of capital, K, and labour, L. However, in the
    short run K can be assumed to be fixed and so Q is then a function of L alone.
    In this instance, Q is referred to as the short run production function. The
    independent variable L is usually measured in terms of the number of workers
    or the number of worker hours. The derivative of the production function with
    respect to L, known as the marginal product of labour (MPL), measures
    the rate at which output changes as the number of workers increases. Thus, we
    have
    MPL = dQ
    dL
    . (6.19)
    Economists say that MPL is approximately the change in output resulting from
    a one unit increase in labour.
    Example 6.10
    For the production function
    Q = 8

    L,
    find the marginal product of labour. Determine the output and the marginal
    product of labour when
  8. L = 1,
  9. L = 4,
  10. L = 100.
    130 Elements of Mathematics for Economics and Finance
    20 40 60 80 100
    0
    20
    40
    60
    80 Q
    L
    Figure 6.3 Graph of the production function Q = 8L1/2.
    Solution. The marginal product of labour is found by differentiating Q =
    8L1/2. This gives, using the power function rule,
    MPL = dQ
    dL
    = 8× 1
    2L1/2−1 = 4L
    −1/2 =
    4
    L1/2 .
  11. When L = 1, Q = 8 and MPL = 4.
  12. When L = 4, Q = 16 and MPL = 2.
  13. When L = 100, Q = 80 and MPL = 0.4.
    As L increases from 0, so does output (see Fig. 6.3). However, MPL decreases
    and therefore although output increases, it does so at a decreasing rate. In this
    situation, we say that there are diminishing returns to labour.
    Example 6.11
    Consider the production function is
    Q = 120

    L − 5L,
    where Q denotes output and L denotes the size of the workforce. Calculate the
    value of MPL when
  14. L = 1,
  15. L = 16,
  16. L = 100,
  17. L = 900,
    and discuss the implication of these results.
  18. Differentiation 131
    50 100 150
    0
    50
    100
    150
    Q
    L
    Figure 6.4 Graph of the production function Q = 60

    L − 5L.
    Solution. The marginal product of labour, MPL, is found by differentiating
    the production function with respect to L. This gives
    MPL = dQ
    dL
    = 120 × 1
    2L1/2−1 − 5 = 60L
    −1/2 −5 =
    60
    L1/2
    − 5.
  19. When L = 1, MPL = 55.
  20. When L = 16, MPL = 10.
  21. When L = 100, MPL = 1,
  22. When L = 900, MPL = −3.
    In the last part of this example, we see that a size of workforce is reached that,
    if exceeded, actually results in a decrease in output. This may seem counterintuitive
    at first sight. However, this situation can occur in production processes
    where productivity is diminished due to problems of overcrowding on the shop
    floor or the need to create an elaborate administration to organize the larger
    workforce. The graph of this production function is sketched in Fig. 6.4.
    The production function in the last example satisfies what is known as the
    law of diminishing marginal productivity. This law, also known as the law
    of diminishing returns, states that the increase in output due to a one unit
    increase in labour will eventually decline. A typical production function that
    satisfies this law is shown in Fig. 6.5. The graph of the corresponding marginal
    product of labour, MPL, is shown in Fig. 6.6. Note that the maximum value of
    MPL is attained when L = L0 and MPL = 0 at the value of L corresponding
    to maximum production.
    132 Elements of Mathematics for Economics and Finance
    A
    B
    C D
    Q
    Lo L
    Figure 6.5 Graph illustrating a production function that satisfies the law
    of diminishing marginal productivity.
    Between L = 0 and L = L0, the curve bends upwards, becoming progressively
    steeper and so the slope, MPL, of the production function increases.
    Mathematically speaking,
    d(MPL)
    dL

0,
MP
Lo L
L
Figure 6.6 Graph of marginal product of labour corresponding to the
production function shown in Fig. 6.5.

  1. Differentiation 133
    or, since MPL = dQ/dL,
    d2Q
    dL2 > 0,
    i.e., if we take any two points A: (L1,Q(L1)) and B: (L2,Q(L2)) on the curve
    between the points (0, 0) and (L0,Q(L0)) with L1 < L2, then the slope of the tangent at B is greater than that at A (see Fig. 6.5). Similarly, for L > L0 the
    curve of the production function bends downwards and the slope of the slope
    function decreases and is negative, i.e.,
    d2Q
    dL2 < 0, i.e., if we take any two points C: (L3,Q(L3)) and D: (L4,Q(L4)) on the curve beyond the point (L0,Q(L0)) with L3 < L4, then the slope of the tangent at C is greater than that at D (see Fig. 6.5). The law of diminishing returns states that this must happen eventually, i.e., d2Q dL2 < 0, for L > L0.
    Example 6.12
    Show that the law of diminishing marginal productivity holds for the production
    function
    Q = 15L2 − 0.2L3.
    Solution. Differentiating the production function gives
    MPL = dQ
    dL
    = 30L − 0.6L2.
    Differentiating a second times gives
    d2Q
    dL2 = 30 − 1.2L.
    The expression defining the second derivative, i.e., 30−1.2L becomes negative
    when 30 − 1.2L < 0, i.e., when L >
    30
    1.2
    = 25.
    Therefore, the law of diminishing marginal productivity holds for this production
    function for L > 25, i.e., L0 = 25.
    134 Elements of Mathematics for Economics and Finance
    EXERCISES
    6.1. Find the derivatives of the following functions:
    a) f(x) = 4,
    b) f(x) = 4×3,
    c) f(x) = x8,
    d) f(x) = 2×3/2,
    e) f(x) = 3x + 7.
    6.2. Find dy/dx for each of the following:
    a) y = 5+2x − 3×2,
    b) y = x3 + 3×2 + 5,
    c) y = x2 + 5,
    d) y = x4 − 3×2 + 1.
    6.3. Find the first and second derivatives of the following functions:
    a) y = e4x,
    b) y = 3e−2x.
    Evaluate these derivatives when x = 0.
    6.4. Find the first and second derivatives of the following functions:
    a) y = ln4x,
    b) y = 2ln7x.
    Evaluate these derivatives when x = 1.
    6.5. If TC = 3Q2+7Q+12, find expressions for the marginal and average
    cost functions. Evaluate them when Q = 3 and Q = 5.
    6.6. For each of the following demand functions, find expressions for TR
    and MR and evaluate them when Q = 4 and Q = 10.
    a) Q = 36 − 2P,
    b) 44 − 4P − Q = 0.
    6.7. Find the first and second derivatives of the function
    y = 6×3 − 20×2 − 9x + 12.
    Evaluate these derivatives when x = 1.
  2. Differentiation 135
    6.8. Find the marginal cost function for the average cost function given
    by
    AC = 3
    2Q+4+ 46
    Q .
    6.9. The fixed costs of producing a good are 50 and the variable costs
    are 2 + 1
    4Q per unit.
    a) Find expressions for TC and MC.
    b) Evaluate TC and MC when Q = 20. Hence estimate the change
    in TC brought about by a 2 unit increase in output from the
    current level of 20 units.
    6.10. If the consumption function is
    C = 0.03Y 2 + 0.1Y + 30
    calculate MPC and MPS when Y = 4 and give an interpretation
    of the results.
    6.11. Show that the law of diminishing marginal productivity holds for
    the production function
    Q = 18L2 − 0.6L3.

[Button id=”1″]


[ad_2]
Source link

"96% of our customers have reported a 90% and above score. You might want to place an order with us."

Essay Writing Service
Affordable prices

You might be focused on looking for a cheap essay writing service instead of searching for the perfect combination of quality and affordable rates. You need to be aware that a cheap essay does not mean a good essay, as qualified authors estimate their knowledge realistically. At the same time, it is all about balance. We are proud to offer rates among the best on the market and believe every student must have access to effective writing assistance for a cost that he or she finds affordable.

Caring support 24/7

If you need a cheap paper writing service, note that we combine affordable rates with excellent customer support. Our experienced support managers professionally resolve issues that might appear during your collaboration with our service. Apply to them with questions about orders, rates, payments, and more. Contact our managers via our website or email.

Non-plagiarized papers

“Please, write my paper, making it 100% unique.” We understand how vital it is for students to be sure their paper is original and written from scratch. To us, the reputation of a reliable service that offers non-plagiarized texts is vital. We stop collaborating with authors who get caught in plagiarism to avoid confusion. Besides, our customers’ satisfaction rate says it all.

© 2022 Homeworkcrew.com provides writing and research services for limited use only. All the materials from our website should be used with proper references and in accordance with Terms & Conditions.

Scroll to Top